In the late 1970s and throughout the 1980s, an active political movement
emerged on the streets of Iran's largest cities. Poor people began to
construct their own communities on unused urban lands, creating an
infrastructure----roads, electricity, running water, garbage collection,
and shelters----all their own. As the Iranian government attempted to
evict these illegal settlers, they resisted----fiercely and ultimately
successfully. This is the story of their economic and political
strategies.
Click here to download this book in pdf.
Asef Bayat, Street Politics: Poor People’s Movements in Iran (Columbia University Press, 1997)
Reviewed by Peyman Vahabzadeh
The Rain 4:2 (Summer-Autumn 2006): 6
One of the merits of Assef Bayat’s Street Politics rests
in the pursuit of showing the continuity of
movements of urban disenfranchised across defining political thresholds
in a country whose modern experience of politics has always involved
revolutionary or liberation movements. The history of the twentieth
century Iran attests to the fact that political stability lasts no
longer than a generation’s life-span and each new generation brings with
it, and vehemently tries to implement, its own vision of the future.
It is easy, so to speak, to lose sight of movements that are not by any
standard étatiste or are strategically unorganized or “spontaneous”.
Bayat’s study shows that the movements of urban disenfranchised,
misplaced, poor, and squatter-dwellers in Iran are symptomatic of
mutant developmental projects under both the ancien regime of the Shah
and the current Islamic Republic. His aim is “to recover and give
agency to one of those suppressed voiced, that of the urban
disenfranchised” (5). The “quiet encroachment of the ordinary”, as the
author calls movements of the urban poor, bears only indirect political
implications, but it “implies changes that the actors consider ...
significant in themselves without intending necessarily to undermine
political authority. Yet these very simple and everyday practices are
bound to shift into the realm of politics” (8).
Sociologically, the phenomenon of rural-urban migration in its
present form markedly started in
the 1950s and was accelerated during the 1960s, thanks to the Shah’s
land reform intended to enter into world capitalist system, supposedly
as a strong, but in fact only a peripheral, participant. Making family
subsistence based on land impossible in the face of growing agribusiness
or agglomeration of small lands in few hands, his reforms detached
rural laborers from their traditional niches, forcing them to seek
employment in the then newly-emerging industrial sector. An all but
familiar trend. By the 1970s, the phenomenon of the “new poor” was more
than visible and the new urban poor, these victims of “maldevelopment”
or “pseudomodernization” were treated by the state as villains of
development (23). Bayat
estimates that by 1980 in Tehran alone at least thirty-five percent
of the city’s population lived in
slums, squats and makeshift settlements (29). To maintain the image
of a modern Iran, the Shah’s
regime made consistent efforts to push back squatter-dwellers to the
unnoticeable outskirts of
Tehran and other big cities, never hesitating to use force to achieve
such ends. The “problem” of
the urban poor eventually came to the fore as a political issue in
the 1977 bloody confrontation
outside the municipality of Rey (south of Tehran) in which
squatter-dwellers defending their homes spontaneously clashed with the
gendarmerie forces and municipal bulldozers that had orders to level
all illegal constructions. What added to the significance of this
incident was the vivid politicization of the issue when a team of the
Marxist Fadaian urban guerrillas bombed the municipality building in
Rey in solidarity with urban toilers and squatter-dwellers (43).
The populist language of the Islamic Revolution of 1979, however,
uplifted the scorned image of
the new poor by calling them mustaz’afin (a Koranic expression)—the
downtrodden—in an
attempt at winning over this growing but alienated segment of the
Iranian population. Seeking to
give Islam a populist and emancipatory image, Ayatollah Khomeini
personally and repeatedly
called the Revolution one of the downtrodden and squatter-dwellers
(gowdneshinan) (35). In the
face of a revolutionary but modern, liberal and westernized middle
class, a working class that had
historical ties with the Left, and regions, ethnicities and
minorities that treated the idea of a Shi’i
state with great suspicion, the leaders of the Revolution had no
alternative but to appeal to the
urban poor as the authentic people. The new poor were propagated as
devoutly religious people with strong ties to traditional ways of life,
people who bore the disdain of westernization and piously lived in
communities of the dispossessed. The urban poor and squatter-dwellers
almost by
default became the standard bearers of the revolutionary promise.
In the aftermath of the subversion of monarchy in Iran, radical
populism and the early revolutionary spirit facilitated the permeation
of the urban poor into the big cities and notably into wealthier
neighborhoods. In many cases the new wave of re-migration led to the
occupation of the abandoned hotels, villas and mansions that belonged
to the former regime’s top functionaries (chapter four).
Notwithstanding the revolutionary promise and its idealization of the
urban poor as the authentic people, the situation of the urban poor was
exacerbated following the Revolution and war with Iraq: soon eviction
orders were delivered and enforced by the Revolutionary Guards (67-74).
In the absence of independent formal organizations, social
mobilization fell into the hands of local neighborhood councils and
Islamic consumer cooperatives, formed following the Revolution, that
were informally state-sponsored (41, 52-58). Various leftist groups
started organizing and mobilizing shantytown dwellers, but eventually
to no avail, thanks to the general repression of all opposition
beginning in 1981.
The Islamic state’s response to the problem of the new poor mainly
hinged on the institutionalization of the relationship between the
urban unprivileged and the state. As Bayat observes: “Whereas the poor
viewed migration as a means to a better life, for the authorities it
represented a ‘social catastrophe’, ‘the most important problem beside
the war [with Iraq]’, and ‘a major threat to the revolution and the
Islamic Republic’” (101). The newly formed Housing Foundation provided
limited provisions (100). Given the structural failure as well as the
government’s repeated policy fiascoes in deterring migrants from
settling on the outskirts of the big cities, and given the political
cost of a confrontational approach with the poor, quiet policies such
as reforestation of vacant lands outside Tehran are now implemented
(108).
But such policies can only address part of the problem. Expectedly,
the squatter phenomenon of
such magnitude as it exists in Iran always comes with problems of
rampant unemployment and the subsequent visible growth of an informal
economy featuring smugglers of goods, merchandise brokers, street
vendors, and a vast unregulated service sector. Due to their connection
with the growing labour movement in the months following the
Revolution, the unemployed managed to stage protest movements, which
only achieved meagre results before ceding into the suppressive, but
transient, postrevolutionary political climate of the summer of 1979
(chapter six). However, given the obstinacy of unemployment and the
presence of street vendors in the 1990s the City of Tehran tried to
regulate and organize “committed” vendors (by issuing them licenses)
into scheduled day markets, now dubbed “traditional markets” (154)—a
practice in lifting the “burden” of employment off the state that is
well in place in France, Italy and many other countries today.
As an attempt at mapping out the new poor as underrepresented social
actors, Bayat’s study demystifies the notions of the “passive poor” as
well as the so-called “natural alliance” between the Islamic state and
the religious poor (158-159). In fact, Bayat points out that the new
poor are politically divided: some are incorporated by the state
(namely into the Revolutionary Guards, the paramilitary Basiji corps,
or the Construction Crusade), but “[m]ost of the poor seem to be
uninterested in any particular form of ideology and politics” (159).
In any case, rational calculation and hopes for a better future remain
the defining characteristics of movements of the poor, and Bayat’s book
offers a valuable study of the informal, street politics of the new
poor in Iran.
The study also raises two critical points that deserve further
discussion (which this review does
not claim to embark on). First, Bayat frequently makes reference to
the problem of the urban poor and squatter-dwellers as a specifically
Third World problem. He analogizes the Iranian case with that of Egypt
(21, 155, 158-59) and Latin America (21, 41-42, 87) in order to assert
the “maldevelopmental” roots of the phenomenon. While one need not deny
such structural political economy approaches to the problem of the
urban poor and displaced (which always implies an ideal image of
development) by widening one’s comparative scope—that is, by making
analogies with European and North American cases of the urban poor,
homeless, and cardboard-box, back-alley dwellers—one can indeed take
the issue beyond explaining rural-urban migration and squatterdwelling
in terms of the flaws of capitalist incorporation of labour power.
Stated differently, while the problem of the “new poor” can be traced to
the industrialization of peripheral economies in a capitalist world
system (which is the case in Iran), the issue in fact reveals the
problem of modern urbanization. This brings us to the second point: the
urban monster is both a blessing and a curse for modern politics.
Without urbanization, modern forms of power, political representation
and liberal democracy would not have been possible. But at the same
time, as an original institution modern politics presupposes a
normative, civic, labour-based, and free-enterprise-oriented public.
Naturally, those who do not fit in these urbane axes of citizenship
disturb the smooth functioning of the political apparatus because,
among other things, they cannot be socially located. Thus, from the
dominant utilitarian view of politics, prevalent where the modern state
is in place, the urban poor produce no “meaningful” political
participation, precisely because those who cannot “dwell” within the
urban organization of politics according to the above axes of civic
participation cannot be politically significant either. And this is the
source of political underrepresentation of the poor, a problem that in
liberal democratic regimes can be addressed by bridging the gap between
the “people on the ground” and activists. In countries like Iran,
where authoritarian states try to steal the representation of the poor
and squatterdwellers from genuine grassroots social activists, the
movement of the poor inevitably oscillates between, on the one hand,
political refusal that involves prolonged and agonizing negotiations
with—and protest movements against—all levels of government around
local demands and specific issues, and on the other, the spontaneous
political show of “people’s power” and direct, at times revolutionary,
confrontation with the state.