Most accounts of the Marikana massacre, and the resulting
turmoil in the South African mining industry, stress the ongoing importance of
structural poverty, and the gross inequalities of life in South Africa after
the end of Apartheid. If the writers on this subject (and many other events of
contemporary South African politics) are correct, little has changed. But they
are not right, at least not straightforwardly. The violent protests on the
mines have been prompted by very dramatic changes in the distribution of power
on the mines, changes that have brought about conditions of civil war within
the mines’ unionised work force. And what that internecine conflict shows is
that the long-term structures of political economy that supported the mines,
and the distinctive features created by Apartheid South Africa, present an
unexpected threat to the union movement, mining capital and the state.
The most influential scholarly account of the making of the Apartheid state was published as the first article in the new journal Economy and Society in 1972. In this explanation Harold Wolpe heavily emphasised the changing relationship between two distinct regional modes of production, one emerging from the mines organised by thoroughly capitalist relations of production, the other in the tribal reserves based on communally held land and production organised and controlled by families. He endorsed the argument, long made by South African scholars, that capitalist development had been subsidized by migrancy directly by cheapening the cost of labour and indirectly by transferring the burden of social reproduction on to families trapped in the tribal reserves. What was distinctive about his analysis was his claim that the communal economy in the reserves was collapsing and that the coercive apparatus of Apartheid, with its massive investment in policing, prisons and influx control, was required to maintain the return flow of migrant labourers.
The most influential scholarly account of the making of the Apartheid state was published as the first article in the new journal Economy and Society in 1972. In this explanation Harold Wolpe heavily emphasised the changing relationship between two distinct regional modes of production, one emerging from the mines organised by thoroughly capitalist relations of production, the other in the tribal reserves based on communally held land and production organised and controlled by families. He endorsed the argument, long made by South African scholars, that capitalist development had been subsidized by migrancy directly by cheapening the cost of labour and indirectly by transferring the burden of social reproduction on to families trapped in the tribal reserves. What was distinctive about his analysis was his claim that the communal economy in the reserves was collapsing and that the coercive apparatus of Apartheid, with its massive investment in policing, prisons and influx control, was required to maintain the return flow of migrant labourers.
A few years later Monica Wilson, the matriarch of South
African liberal scholarship and author of a brilliant and withering
anthropology of Pondoland, the archetypal labour reserve, explained to a
Johannesburg audience that the ability of rural African families to subsidize
the economic development in the cities had come to its end. ‘South Africa has
lived on the capital of a very strong African family system,’ she warned, ‘and
that capital has been squandered’ (p. 18). Like Wolpe she argued that the coercive
arrangements that were required to maintain the economy of migrant labour were
destroying the liberal foundations of urban society and families in the
countryside. The ‘first aim’ of a sane and responsible social policy, she
argued, ‘must be the settlement of families at the breadwinner’s place of
work.’
Since the early 1980s, social historians, especially based
here at Wits, have presented a somewhat different account of the political
agency of migrancy. They have shown how workers invested determinedly in the
increasingly impossible project of the rural homestead, opting for strategies
that bolstered the chances of rural independence and taking control of
institutions like chiefship, compounds and prisons that were designed to subdue
them. Charles van Onselen’s biographical essay on the prison gang leader
Nongoloza Mathebula (requires subscription) in History Workshop in 1985
captured the entangled politics of this research eloquently. The scholarly
picture of migrant labour is now intriguingly dialectical with the state, the
largest industrial employers and millions of poor rural men heavily invested in
the increasingly fictional project of rural independence from capitalism. Yet,
despite the enormous field of excellent research, both the state and social
scientists seem to have very significantly underestimated the politics and
significance of migrancy today.
What the South African mining industry is now facing, as
former unionist Gavin Hartford has recently demonstrated in a paper that has
electrified the country, is unmistakably an angry revolt of male migrant
labourers, quite distinct from the much larger body of urban men and women who
make up the bulk of the mining work force. The workers driving the bitter
disputes on the mines are almost entirely Rock Drill Operators, or, in the
technical language of the mines, they are RDOs. These are the men (almost
entirely) who do the miserably dangerous but indispensable work of driving the
heavy pneumatic drills deep in to the quartzite rock that encases the gold and
platinum. They were recruited from the traditional labour reserves of the South
African mining industry, from Lesotho, Mozambique and the Eastern Cape. The
most significant portion are from the Eastern Cape district of Pondoland, the
region that formed the subject of Monica Wilson’s Reaction to Conquest, and
which has served as a laboratory for the social science of migrancy ever since
(with excellent work by the Mayers, William Beinart and Dunbar Moodie).
What is distinctive about these RDOs is their basic
illiteracy which (although it has some of the virtues claimed by James Scott)
traps them in to the job categories, and career trajectories, that used to be
all that was available to black men on the mines. They cannot meet the academic
requirements to become Miners (the skilled workers, and, not incidentally, the
old job category that was reserved for whites), or any of the other skilled
work positions, and they are trapped in a model of unskilled migrant labour
that was first developed over a century ago. As Hartford and others show, the
revolt is being led by migrants who have worked on the mines for decades, the
majority of whom are in their late 40s or early 50s.
These men nurture the dream of returning to live permanently
in the countryside. They have in mind a rural world that has few of the
resources of the capitalist cities but many of the virtues of the precapitalist
commons. The schools, hospitals, telephones and roads in Pondoland are in a
state of horrible dishevelment. But the homesteads there, like the others in
the tribal lands, are also free (aside from a nominal and mostly unenforced
tribal levy) of the onerous costs of living in a capitalist world. There is,
usually, no electricity, and hence no electricity bill. Water comes, mostly,
from the sky or from the rivers. And there are no municipal rates, rentals or
mortgages on property.
Yet the reality of migrancy bears little resemblance to the
life of the commons. A generation ago, migrant labourers were housed in
single-sex compounds that best resembled low-security prisons. These grim
institutions had the outstanding benefit of sheltering migrants from the
demands of urban capitalism. They paid no rent, their food was provided by the
mines and even their entertainment, such as it was, was subsidized in the
compound. But the compounds did not survive the end of Apartheid. In the
effort, very belatedly, to meet Monica Wilson’s demand to house families near
to their workers, the mines offered to subsidize local housing. But they also
offered the migrants the choice of a small ‘living-out allowance’ in place of a
housing subsidy. It was this amount, around $200 per month, which migrants used
to set up a home in one of the shanty-towns that now surround all of the mines.
Typically moving in with a woman, the migrants were quickly subject to the
fierce cost pressures of urban South African life. In the wake of the Marikana
massacre the National Credit Regulator raided the premises of the 13
micro-lenders in the area, accusing the companies of encouraging workers to
take on unrealistic debts, and making use of blank garnishing orders to secure
repayment prior to the issue of salaries.
Here, also, lie the reasons for the migrants’ murderous
anger at the National Union of Mineworkers, the union that has probably done
more to create the free South Africa than any other organisation or
institution. NUM, at least until recently, represented a majority of workers on
the platinum and gold mines. Many of those workers are in skilled positions
that pay well, and which have a clear path for promotion and salary
improvements. (When the RDOs demand a monthly salary after deductions of
R12,500, or approximately £1,000, they have in mind the current earnings of
Miners.) NUM officials have also become part of the managerial hierarchy on the
mines, paying themselves well and drawing on privileges and facilities not
available to unskilled workers. In the recent salary negotiations at both Impala
Platinum and Lonmin, managers, aware of the growing gap between skilled and
unskilled union members, attempted to impose special salary and bonus increases
specifically for the RDOs. It was NUM’s rejection of those increases at both
mines that precipitated the strikes, and the migrants’ flight to the mountains
of Marikana.
There can be no doubt that many mistakes have been made in
the reaction to the RDOs withdrawal from work at Impala Platinum early in
January this year. The Minister of Mines is probably correct to be furious with
managers at both Impala and Lonmin for agreeing to increases to strikers who
were not members of a recognised union and, most importantly, completely
outside of a bargaining structure that has taken decades to evolve. The effect
was simultaneously to shred both the recently negotiated wage contracts and the
legitimacy of the NUM, which now faces a struggle for its life. Another
critical mistake followed the brutal killings of NUM organisers and police. For
decades the union has exploited the forms of horrible retributional violence
that have been nurtured by migrants and their institutions. Yet just three days
before the Marikana massacre, the Secretary General of NUM, a figure of
singular power in South Africa, called for ‘a special task force or the [Army]
to deal decisively with the criminal elements in Rustenburg.’ And the police
commanders utterly misread the crowd-control requirements for handling
thousands of adult men armed to the teeth with the weapons of a fondly remembered
regimental past.
But the biggest mistakes are much older. These concern, as
Hartford has shown, the appalling neglect of migrancy in the gold and platinum
industries. His point is that migrancy is the norm in mining everywhere, for
the simple reason that human populations do not settle in the areas of valuable
mineral deposits. But the South African mining industry has been operating with
a model of migrancy that presumes workers without citizenship. The RDOs work,
for example, for 11 months at a time, returning to their rural homes only over
Christmas. There are no facilities for short time contracts, return visits, or
even the sorts of decent dormitory housing that are typical in enclave mines
throughout the African continent. The remedies are obvious. What is not clear
is that the South African mining industry will actually last long enough to
implement them.